• Nikoniko Homestay (にこにこHomestay)

    Feb 17, 2025

  • Steve Keen on Economic Ideology, Capitalism, and the Future

    In this comprehensive discussion, we explore the intricate web of economic ideologies, the challenges posed by capitalism, and the pressing need for a paradigm shift in our approach to economics. Steve Keen, a renowned economist, delves into the flaws of neoclassical economics, the necessity of addressing climate change, and the potential for a new economic system that prioritizes sustainability and equity.

    Table of Contents

    Intro

    In the landscape of economics, there exists a plethora of ideas and theories that shape our understanding of markets and human behavior. Yet, amidst this complexity, one question persists: are we truly grasping the essence of economic realities? This inquiry leads us to examine the frameworks that dominate economic thought, particularly the neoclassical paradigm, and the implications of clinging to outdated models. By dissecting these theories, we can unveil the discrepancies between economic assumptions and the actual workings of markets.

    The Parry Boss

    The concept of the "Parry Boss" is emblematic of the idealized market scenario often portrayed by traditional economists. This theoretical auctioneer is imagined to adjust prices in response to supply and demand, driving markets toward equilibrium. However, this simplistic view overlooks the intricate interdependencies between different commodities. For instance, a price increase in pears can ripple through the market, affecting the prices of pigs and steel simultaneously. This interconnectedness challenges the notion that markets can effortlessly achieve equilibrium through the actions of a hypothetical auctioneer.

    Moreover, the assumption that all price changes will ultimately lead to stability is fundamentally flawed. The mathematical models developed to support this idea have revealed that the conditions necessary for convergence do not hold in reality. In fact, these models indicate that the process is inherently unstable, leading to the conclusion that if we wait for markets to reach equilibrium, we risk inaction and stagnation.

    Are Economists Scientists?

    The classification of economists as scientists is a contentious topic. While they may employ scientific methods in their research, the underlying paradigms they adhere to often lack the adaptability characteristic of true scientific inquiry. Economists, particularly those entrenched in neoclassical thought, tend to operate within a rigid framework that dismisses anomalies rather than addressing them. This behavior mirrors the historical trajectory of scientific progress, where paradigms must evolve in response to emerging evidence.

    In this light, the neoclassical economists can be seen as scientists in name but not in practice. Their refusal to acknowledge the limitations of their models stifles genuine progress in the discipline. For instance, many economists cling to the theory of diminishing marginal productivity, despite overwhelming empirical evidence contradicting it. This exemplifies a broader trend within the field, where adherence to established theories takes precedence over the pursuit of truth.

    Is Economics a Science?

    The question of whether economics qualifies as a science hinges on its ability to adapt and respond to new information. Traditional economic theories often present themselves as scientific due to their mathematical underpinnings and academic legitimacy. However, the persistent reliance on outdated models raises doubts about the discipline's scientific status. If economics cannot evolve in the face of contradictory evidence, can it truly be considered a science?

    In contrast, fields like physics or biology thrive on constantly refining their theories based on empirical data. Economics, particularly neoclassical economics, often resists this evolution, leading to a disconnect between theory and reality. While some branches of economics, such as ecological economics, strive to adopt a more scientific approach by incorporating real-world complexities, the dominant paradigms remain entrenched in outdated assumptions.

    Why Are Factories So Cheap?

    The question of why factories can produce goods at such low costs is tied to the myth of diminishing marginal productivity. Traditional economic models suggest that as production increases, the cost per unit rises due to inefficiencies. However, empirical studies consistently demonstrate that the opposite is true: many factories operate under conditions of constant or even falling marginal costs.

    This phenomenon can be attributed to several factors. First, factories are designed with capacity for growth, allowing them to operate efficiently even as production scales up. Second, fixed costs are distributed over a larger number of units, leading to lower average costs per unit as output increases. This reality starkly contrasts with the neoclassical assumption that higher output inevitably leads to rising costs.

    Additionally, the failure of economic textbooks to incorporate these empirical findings perpetuates a cycle of misinformation. By ignoring the realities of production costs, economists hinder the development of sound economic policies and practices. The disconnect between theory and practice ultimately undermines the credibility of the discipline as a whole.

    Other Economists Who Are Not Scientists

    While some economists may fit the mold of scientists, many others do not. A significant portion of the discipline remains entrenched in outdated paradigms that lack empirical support. For instance, the post-Keynesian school, which emphasizes the importance of real-world complexities, offers a more realistic approach to understanding economic phenomena. However, it often grapples with the remnants of neoclassical thought that dominate mainstream economics.

    Moreover, the tendency for economists to reinforce their beliefs through selective teaching and research further complicates the landscape. When anomalies arise, rather than reevaluating their theories, many economists choose to ignore or downplay them. This behavior is reminiscent of artists who create within a confined framework, adhering to established norms rather than challenging them.

    Ultimately, the question arises: if a significant portion of economists is not engaging with reality, what does that mean for the discipline? The implications are profound, as misguided theories can shape policies that affect millions. This disconnect between theory and reality underscores the need for a critical reevaluation of economic thought.

    Running Away from Reality

    The phenomenon of "running away from reality" is a recurring theme in economic discourse. When faced with evidence that contradicts established theories, many economists choose to ignore or dismiss it. This behavior is most clearly illustrated in the case of Alan Blinder, who conducted a comprehensive survey on firm costs, only to find that the overwhelming majority of production occurs under conditions contrary to the neoclassical assumptions of rising marginal costs.

    Instead of integrating these findings into his teachings, Blinder reverted to traditional textbook narratives that failed to reflect the empirical realities he uncovered. This pattern of behavior raises critical questions about the integrity of economic research and the responsibility of economists to engage with the truth.

    Moreover, the reluctance to confront uncomfortable truths can be likened to the behavior of religious fundamentalists who reject scientific findings that challenge their beliefs. In both cases, the stakes are high: the failure to adapt can lead to stagnation and a failure to address pressing economic issues. The persistence of outdated theories not only hampers academic progress but also has real-world implications that can adversely affect economic policy and societal welfare.

    Economics is Not a Science

    Economics has long been mischaracterized as a science. Traditional economists often assert their theories with a confidence that mirrors the rigor of the natural sciences. Yet, this perception is misleading. The neoclassical approach, which dominates the field, operates more like a set of beliefs rather than a discipline committed to the scientific method.

    In genuine sciences, theories are constantly tested and revised in light of new evidence. However, in economics, particularly neoclassical economics, outdated models persist despite overwhelming evidence that contradicts them. This creates a paradox: while economists may employ mathematical tools, the foundational assumptions often remain unchallenged, stifling progress.

    Economics is Like Theology

    Drawing a parallel between economics and theology may seem unconventional, but the comparison is striking. Both fields are built on foundational beliefs that resist contradiction. Just as theology holds certain doctrines sacred, economics often clings to neoclassical principles as if they were dogma.

    In this light, economics resembles a belief system where core tenets dictate the interpretation of data. The reluctance to abandon these principles, even in the face of anomalies, reflects a commitment to a paradigm that feels utopian. Economists often ignore evidence that challenges their worldview, much like theologians may dismiss findings that contradict their faith.

    Who is Steve Keen?

    Steve Keen is a prominent figure in the critique of mainstream economic thought. With a background in both economics and physics, Keen brings a unique perspective that challenges conventional wisdom. His work focuses on the flaws inherent in neoclassical models, advocating for a more dynamic understanding of economic systems.

    Keen's approach emphasizes the importance of debt and its role in economic cycles, a concept often overlooked by traditional economists. By integrating insights from complexity theory and systems dynamics, he offers a fresh lens through which to view economic phenomena. Keen is not merely an academic; he is a passionate advocate for a paradigm shift in economics.

    Why is This Stuff Happening?

    The persistence of flawed economic models can be attributed to several factors. One significant reason is the entrenched nature of academic institutions, which often prioritize established theories over innovative ideas. Economists who challenge the status quo may find themselves marginalized within their own field.

    Moreover, the allure of a utopian vision—where free markets are seen as inherently superior—creates a barrier to change. This belief system is reinforced by success stories that align with neoclassical principles, overshadowing instances where these models fail to explain real-world events. The reluctance to embrace new paradigms stifles discourse and limits the exploration of alternative approaches to understanding the economy.

    The Nobel Prize for Economics

    The Nobel Prize for Economics, often touted as a hallmark of achievement, is a curious construct. Unlike the original Nobel Prizes, which were established by Alfred Nobel himself, the economics prize was created by the Swedish Central Bank in 1968. This distinction raises questions about its legitimacy as a scientific accolade.

    The prize has been awarded to economists who have made significant contributions to the neoclassical framework, reinforcing the dominance of this paradigm. However, the very fact that it is funded by a central bank reflects a bias towards maintaining the status quo. Critics argue that the prize perpetuates a narrow view of economics, sidelining alternative perspectives that could enrich the discipline.

    Why Didn't He Quit Economics?

    Despite recognizing the limitations of mainstream economics, Steve Keen chose not to abandon the field. His decision stems from a deep-seated belief in the potential for meaningful change within economics. Keen's journey through academia revealed a vibrant community of dissenting voices—those who, like him, questioned the validity of neoclassical assumptions.

    Rather than retreating from the discipline, Keen engaged with alternative theories and sought to enrich the discourse. His commitment to challenging established norms has positioned him as a key figure in the movement for a more inclusive and realistic approach to economics.

    Origins of Economics

    The origins of economics can be traced back to influential thinkers like Adam Smith and Karl Marx, who laid the groundwork for modern economic thought. However, the evolution of the field has often overlooked critical contributions from earlier schools of thought, such as the physiocrats. These early economists emphasized the role of land and natural resources as sources of wealth, a perspective that resonates with contemporary discussions surrounding sustainability and resource management.

    As economics developed, debates between classical and neoclassical theories emerged, shaping the trajectory of the discipline. The neoclassical shift, which redefined value through the lens of marginal productivity, overshadowed earlier insights. This historical context is essential for understanding the current state of economic thought and the need for a reevaluation of foundational principles.

    Neoclassical Economics

    Neoclassical economics emerged as a response to the critiques of classical economics, particularly those put forth by figures like Karl Marx. While classical economists critiqued feudal systems and championed capitalism, neoclassical economists reframed the narrative to defend capitalism against those who questioned its efficacy. They shifted focus from a societal critique to a more individualistic perspective, where utility became the cornerstone of value creation.

    The neoclassical model posits that individuals act to maximize their utility, leading to the assumption that markets naturally find equilibrium. However, this view simplifies complex economic interactions and overlooks the systemic issues that arise within capitalist frameworks. The reliance on subjective utility creates challenges in aggregating individual preferences, leading to a fundamental flaw in the neoclassical approach.

    Pro Capitalism

    Proponents of capitalism argue that it fosters innovation, efficiency, and wealth creation. They claim that the profit motive drives competition, leading to better products and services. However, this perspective often underestimates the social and environmental costs associated with unregulated capitalism.

    While capitalism has indeed spurred remarkable technological advancements, it has also resulted in significant inequalities and environmental degradation. The belief that markets will self-correct ignores the reality of externalities and the exploitation of resources. A more nuanced understanding of capitalism recognizes its strengths but also demands accountability for its shortcomings.

    Why Capitalism?

    Supporters of capitalism argue that it is the most effective economic system for promoting individual freedom and prosperity. They assert that capitalism encourages innovation, as individuals and companies seek to create better products and services to gain a competitive edge. However, this perspective often overlooks the systemic flaws that can arise when profit motives overshadow social responsibility.

    Capitalism, when left unchecked, can lead to monopolies, environmental destruction, and significant social inequalities. The challenge lies in finding a balance between harnessing the benefits of capitalism while implementing regulations that protect the environment and promote social equity. Acknowledging these complexities is essential for developing a sustainable economic future.

    Marx is Wrong

    While Marx's critiques of capitalism highlight valid concerns regarding inequality and exploitation, his predictions about capitalism's inevitable collapse have not materialized. Instead, capitalism has shown a remarkable ability to adapt and evolve. This adaptability, however, does not negate the systemic issues that persist within capitalist structures, such as wealth concentration and environmental degradation.

    Marx's focus on class struggle and the labor theory of value provides valuable insights into the dynamics of power and production. Yet, the evolution of capitalism has demonstrated that the system can persist in various forms, often co-opting dissenting voices into its framework. Thus, while Marx's critiques remain relevant, the notion of capitalism's inevitable downfall lacks empirical support.

    A New Economic System

    The need for a new economic system arises from the recognition that current capitalist frameworks are insufficient for addressing pressing global challenges. Issues such as climate change, inequality, and resource depletion demand innovative solutions that transcend traditional economic paradigms. A new economic system should prioritize sustainability, equity, and resilience.

    Such a system would integrate ecological considerations into economic decision-making, emphasizing the importance of preserving natural resources. By redefining value to include environmental and social factors, we can create an economy that serves the needs of all stakeholders, rather than solely prioritizing profit maximization.

    Capitalism

    Capitalism, as it stands, is a dynamic system characterized by constant change and evolution. While it has facilitated unprecedented levels of wealth creation and innovation, it is also fraught with challenges that threaten its sustainability. The debate surrounding capitalism often centers on its ability to adapt to contemporary issues, such as climate change and social inequality.

    To ensure that capitalism evolves positively, it is crucial to implement regulations that hold corporations accountable for their social and environmental impacts. This approach requires a shift in mindset, moving from a purely profit-driven perspective to one that values long-term sustainability and equitable growth.